Pr
"SUBMISSION
TO THE OFFICE OF FAIR TRADING AND THE COMPETITION COMMISSION"
Mr.
John
Fingleton
Chief Executive
Office of Fair Trading
Fleetbank House
2-6 Salisbury Square
London
EC4Y 8JX
19
February 2009
Dear
Mr. Fingleton,
Enclosed is our submission regarding the Contractual Rights Renewal
Obligations of ITV1.
The
unpredictability and decline in ITV1 revenue since 2004 has
dramatically reduced the profitability of the company requiring
continued cost savings. Further cuts are expected to be announced
on March 4th.
Additionally,
it is generally accepted that the economic climate in the
UK
is
likely to have an adverse effect on the revenue of ITV1 for the
immediate years ahead. This will create further financial pressure
on the company.
In
the paper we point out the competitive and trading environment
within which ITV1 now operates and advance reasons why the CRRs
are no longer appropriate to police the sale of ITV1 airtime,
recommending that they should be removed.
Failure
to do so leaving ITV1 at an unreasonable trading disadvantage.
In
these circumstances it is vital that ITV1 should be allowed to
trade on an appropriate ‘demand led’ basis and unconstrained
in seeking further business from lapsed and new advertisers to
whom the CRRs are irrelevant.
Yours sincerely
Jim
Shaw
Mike Yershon
Joint Chief Executive
Joint Chief Executive
Copy:
Ed Richards OFCOM
|
SUBMISSION TO THE OFFICE OF FAIR TRADING
AND
THE COMPETITION COMMISSION
IN REGARD TO ITV’s
CONTRACTUAL RIGHTS RENEWAL
OBLIGATIONS
19th FEBRUARY 2009
Commercial Television
Associates
1 |
INTRODUCTION,
SUMMARY AND RECOMMENDATION
In this document we have
described the background to the terms of trading by
Granada
and
Carlton
, prior to the merger in 2004, which were incorporated in the
Contract Rights Renewal obligations.
We have identified the basic
economic factors governing the sale of advertising airtime with
which such terms of trading can be seen to be in total conflict
and thus distorting the market.
As we show, ITV today operates
in a highly competitive environment where it competes for programs
and revenue with in excess of 350 channels, many of which are
owned by the worlds largest broadcasting and communications
companies.
It competes with 11 sales
houses.
Since 2003 there has been a
considerable consolidation of the buying groups of which Group M,
Opera, VivaKi and Aegis, all publicly traded international
marketing services companies, now account for over 75% of ITV1s
advertising revenue revenue.
ITV1 airtime is currently seen
to be an essential part of any television schedule with its higher
share of unduplicated audience.
As we point out the price of
television airtime is unarguably demand led. This demand has both
macro and micro influences. The overall level of demand bearing a
strong relationship over time to the growth of GDP whilst the
demand for any station, day of week, time of day, specific break
or position in break reflects the value placed on it by buyers.
Some of these will attract a greater demand and be more valuable
whilst others will be in lesser demand and therefore less
valuable. The collective sum of these values reflecting the
totality of the market.
In 1972 Jim Shaw, then
Director of Sales and Marketing at Thames Television, faced a
freeze on prices by the Conservative Government.
Following meetings with the Board of Trade at which he
explained that, as television airtime sales were demand led, a
freeze on prices would result in the potential rationing of
airtime overall and distortion
in the relative value of its component parts. Subsequently he
constructed an airtime sales system where the overall price of
airtime and its constituent parts floated in response to the
demand from buyers. This proved to be both practical and
efficient.
Later Harry Henry wrote his
papers concerned with the economics of television advertising and
supported this approach to the sale of airtime which he described
as the most appropriate and logical response to it.
In conclusion we would observe
that the contents of the contracts with buyers, the subject of the
CRRs, and the conditions for their modification are clearly
insensitive to the demand for television airtime in general and
particular, and at odds with the economics of television
advertising set out in this document.
As it is the collective
expenditure by buyers which drives the price overall, and within
that the price of one part against another, we propose that the
CRR’s be removed and in parallel ITV1 should adopt a demand led
pricing structure that allows the market to operate efficiently
and be immune from accusations of ‘exploitation of ‘undue
market power’.
Commercial Television
Associates
2
|
SECTIONS
1)
THE ECONOMICS OF THE
SALE
OF TELEVISION ADVERTISING AIRTIME
2)
BACKGROUND TO CONTRACTUAL RIGHTS RENEWAL OBLIGATIONS
3)
COMPETITION
i) Broadcasters competing for programs, audiences and revenue.
ii) Sales Houses
4)
BUYING GROUPS/ CLUBS
5)
THE FRAGMENTATION OF AUDIENCES
6)
HARRY
HENRY PAPERS:
i) ‘Hysteria about television costs: A cyclical ailment.’
ii) ‘The Simple Economics of Television Advertising.’
7)
THE
COMMERCIAL TELEVISION ASSOCIATES.
Commercial Television
Associates
3
|
SECTION
1
THE
ECONOMIC FACTORS RELATING TO THE
SALE
OF AIRTIME
It has already been proved, in theory (see Section 7) and
practice, that the price of airtime is related to the value of the
collective demand from advertisers divided by the number of
minutes of commercial time available. In other words channels
do not set the overall level of demand (and therefore price),
advertisers do!
The value (objectives) of television advertising varies
between advertisers. A car manufacturer may be concerned with the
image they are able to create which leads on to the sale of cars.
on the other hand a company marketing fast moving goods is
probably looking for a direct relationship between investment and
sales whilst Government advertising may seek to condition
attitudes. There is no
one value. the products are different, the sales volumes are
different, the sales margins are different, the total level of
profits engendered are different, the objectives are different.
i) An advertisers budget is not in a static relationship to
expected sales. it is related to their expected profitability
linked to the extent to which production capability matches
consumer demand. stated more simply, if demand exceeds supply
advertisers may spend an increased amount on increased production
capability and less on selling. if supply exceeds demand the
reverse will apply.
ii) The effect of this is that even in a buoyant market
advertisers may spend less on advertising in order to invest more
on increasing production capability.
iii)
Allowing for the affect of the above there is nevertheless a
strong relationship between the growth of gdp and the growth of
advertising over time.
THE
MICRO ECONOMIC FACTORS
Some
breaks will be more desirable collectively to advertisers than
others, as a result of the size of the
audience exposed and their demographic characteristics.
Correspondingly others will be less in demand.
Commercial Television Associates
4
|
SECTION 2
BACKGROUND TO CONTRACT
RIGHTS RENEWAL OBLIGATIONS
Origin of regional ‘station
share of television budgets'.
.
1)
Prior to the commencement of the mergers of the
commercial regional television stations in 1992, stations were
under heavy pressure from buyers to provide concessions in regard
to discounted rates, guaranteed audiences and maximum costs of
audience deliveries, in return for undertakings in regard to their
share of expenditure on television.
The concentration of buying groups elevated the potential losses
to stations not participating in share deals.
2)
For the smaller stations there was the implication
that subject to an acceptable level of concessions they stood the
risk of being totally omitted from advertisers schedules for the
period under negotiation.
3)
The larger stations were exposed to the risk of
diminished revenue.
Over time these special terms
became more and more onerous until they became totally at odds
with the basic economic factors controlling the price of airtime.
Thus utterly distorting the market for television advertising
airtime.
Commercial Television Associates
5
|
COMPETITION
MAJOR TERRESTRIAL CHANNELS
BBC1
BBC2
ITV1
CHANNEL 4
FIVE
CHANNELS AVAILABLE ON CABLE
OR VIA SATELLITE
In excess of 350
Many of these are owned by the
worlds largest broadcasting, media or communications companies.
Company
|
Revenue
|
Net Profit
|
Information
|
Bertelsmann
|
€18.756bn
|
€405bn
|
Privately owned
Germany
company operating internationally.
Owns RTL, the largest broadcasting
group in
Europe
. RTL owns Channel 5 in the
UK
.
|
Bourges
|
€29.613bn
|
€1.376bn
|
Privately owned French company owns TF1
which owns Eurosport.
|
Disney
|
$35.51bn
|
$3.8326bn
|
Major American entertainment, film and
television production company owns ABC Television one of the
major television networks in the
USA
.
|
GE of
America
|
$172.738bn
|
$22.208bn
|
American conglomerate which owns NBC
one of the major networks in the
USA
.
|
Hearst Corporation
|
|
|
Privately owned
US
company. One of the largest diversified communications
companies in the world.
|
Time Warner
|
$46.482bn
|
$4.387bn
|
The worlds second largest media
conglomerate based in the
USA
owns Turner
Broadcasting.
|
Viacom
|
$13.423bn
|
$1.63bn
|
One of the largest global media empires
based in the
USA
. Owns CBS one of the major networks in the
USA
.
|
News Corp
|
$28.66bn
|
$5.381bn
|
Public company based in the
USA
.
The world’s largest media
conglomerate.
|
Commercial Television Associates
6 |
SECTION 3 (ii)
COMPETITION
SALES HOUSES
Channel 4
|
Channel 4
|
E4
|
|
DMS
|
Channel U
Classic FM TV
Game Network
The Horror Channel
|
Motors
NASN (North American Sport)
Rapture TV
|
Real Estate TV
DMS-Baby Channel
Fizz
ABC
|
DOLPHIN
|
All in Sport
Bid TV
Movies 24
Movies4Men
Movies4Men2
More 24
|
Pop
Playboy One
Price Drop TV
Speed Auction
TVTWC
Tiny Pop
|
True Movies
True Movies 2
Zone Reality
Extra
Zone Thriller
Channel U
|
FIVE
|
Five
|
Five
US
|
|
GMTV
|
GMTV
|
|
|
IDS (VIRGIN MEDIA)
|
Bravo
Challenge
Classic FM TV
Extreme Sports
Front Row
FTN
Living TV
Trouble
|
UK
Bright Ideas
UK
Drama
UK
Food
UK
Gold
UKG2
UK
History
UK
Horizons
|
UK
Style
Viacom-TMF
Nickelodeon
Nick Junior
Jetix-Jetix
Turner Boom
Cartoon Network
|
OPTIMAL MEDIA
|
S4C
|
The Golf Channel
|
|
SKY MEDIA
|
Sky 1
Sky Sports 1
Sky Sports 2
Sky Sports 3
Sky News
Sky Premier
Sky Movie Max
Sky Cinema
Sky Travel
History Channel
National Geographic
|
Sky Box Office
Hallmark
Biography
Flaunt
Seuzz
The Amp
Q
Kiss
Kerrang
Magic
Smash Hits
|
MUTV
Adventure One
Animal Planet
Discovery
Civilizations
Discovery Health
Discovery Home and Leisure
Discovery Travel and adventure
Discovery Wings
|
TMH
|
Ben TV
City TV
Channel 7 (
Grimsby
)
Channel 9 (
Londonderry
)
Channel H (
Manchester
)
Christian Inspiration
|
God Channel
God Channel 2
Home TV
Life TV
Oxford
Channel
MA TV (Leicester)
|
My TV
Reality TV
Showcase TV
TBN
Europe
TV12
You TV
|
Commercial Television Associates
7
|
ZIELER MEDIA
|
The Adult Channel
Adult Text
Climax 3
|
Playboy TV
Spice Extreme
|
Private Spice
Trade TV
|
ZMTV
|
B4U Movies
B4U Music
Bangla TV
Channel S
JSTV
|
MATV National
MATV Channel 6
MAX from Sony
Phoenix
Chinese News & Entertainment
|
Sony Entertainment
Television
Asia
TVBS
Europe
(Chinese)
Venue TV
|
Commercial Television
Associates
8
|
SECTION 4
BUYING GROUPS/BUYING CLUBS
Immediately
prior to the merger of
Carlton
and
Granada
in 2004 there
were some 15 top buying points.
Buying Points 2003
|
Mediacom
Mindshare
CIA
Carat
|
Vizeum
Zenith
Starcom
Mediavest
|
Motive
OMD
PHD
Universal McCann
|
Initiative
MPG
Walker
|
Over the five years since the merger and the enforcement of
CRRs dramatic consolidation has occurred amongst the fifteen.
CIA
and Motive are no longer in existence. CIA has been re-branded as
Mediaedge and Motive merged with Starcom.
The
remainder having been consolidated into four major Buying Clubs,
all owned by publicly traded international marketing services
companies These are Group M, OPERA, VivaKi and Aegis, with
substantially increased buying power accounting for over 75% of
ITV1 advertising revenue.
Significantly
transforming the negotiating environment.
In
this situation stations, including that of ITV1, can ill afford a
stand off with any of the clubs.
PARENT
COMPANY
|
BUYING
CLUB
|
BUYING
GROUP BRANDS
|
WPP
|
Group
M
|
Mediacom
Mindshare
Mediaedge
|
OMNICOM
|
Opera
|
OMD
PHD
Rocket
|
Publicis
Groupe
|
VivaKi
|
Starcom
Mediavest
Zenith
|
Aegis
(Havas 29%)
|
Aegis
|
Carat
Vizeum
|
Commercial
Television Associates
9 |
When
trading for each new period begins the Buying Clubs will set out
their requirements for the ‘bulk’ deals.
They
will specify the target audiences based on the TGI analysis and
the trading audience; one of the 15 demographic groups from BARB.
There
will then be discussions as to the discounts to be granted off the
effective station price at the time of delivery, in each of these
categories, and the expected minimum delivery of audience by
category. The proportion and quality of the bulk deal allocated to
any advertiser being under the control of the Buying Group.
Failure
to deliver the agreed level of specified audience will be
compensated by the granting of financial credits. The allocation
of these credits is at the discretion of the Buying Group. Audited
clients and new business being at the front of the queue in this
respect and less demanding un-audited clients at the end.
The effect of this form of
trading is contrary to the basic economics of the airtime sales
market and severely undermines the control ITV1 has over its own
inventory.
Commercial Television Associates
10
|
SECTION 5
FRAGMENTATION OF AUDIENCES
The greatest challenge facing
commercial television broadcasters, financed by the sale of air
time, is the increased fragmentation of audiences.
The objective of any
television advertising campaign is to reach the target audience
with a balance between reaching a satisfactory percentage of the
desired audience and the frequency with which they are exposed to
the advertisement.
With many channels each
attracting an audience, however small, the ability to achieve the
desired ‘reach’ target decreases and is replaced by undue
repetition. The advertising then becomes less efficient and more
costly to achieve the objectives.
For this reason programs with
a higher share of the audience, providing an unduplicated
audience, become essential and consequently more valuable per
rating than those in programs with smaller audiences.
Commercial Television Associates
11
|
SECTION
6
HARRY
HENRY PAPERS
Harry
Henry was a visiting professor of marketing at the
University
of
Bradford
and
at the Cranfield Institute of Technology. He was industrial
professor of marketing and media policy at the International
Management Centre. He chaired the Marketing Communication Research
Centre, the statistics committee of the Advertising Association,
the technical sub-committee of the National Readership Survey, the
research committee of the Evening Newspaper Advertising Bureau and
of British Posters. He was a governor of the History of
Advertising Trust and a member of the editorial boards of the
Journal of Advertising History and the International Journal of
Advertising.
In
1985 he was awarded an honorary D Litt by the Northland Open
University of Canada and in 1988 he received the Market Research
Society’s Gold Medal, both awards recognising his contribution
to management and market research. He won the Advertising
Association’s Mackintosh Medal for his contribution to the
business.
“Hysteria
about television costs: a cyclical ailment’
Harry
Henry offers some help towards understanding more and complaining
less
(ADMAP
May 1997)
Harry
Henry
At
approximately ten-year intervals voices are heard deploring the
shortage of advertising time on television and the iniquitous way
in which television rates have risen (these are usually complained
about as separate phenomena, caused by separate malfeasances,
whereas they are simply reflections one of the other, but let that
pass).
In
1976 the hunt was led chiefly by the media directors of
advertising agencies; in 1988, jointly by spokesmen of Unilever
and Procter & Gamble (at an ISBA conference); and in 1997
(again at an ISBA conference) by Paul Polman, the managing
director of P&G’s
UK
operation. It might be noted that in 1988 we were approaching the
peak of an economic (and hence advertising) cycle; disaster struck
in 1990, and it is to be hoped that the current hue and cry is not
a predictor of an imminent advertising recession, for all that
such recessions are very effective in reducing television costs
per thousand.
Oddly
enough, while between 1988 and 1991 television supply rose by five
per cent, and costs per thousand in real terms fell by 20 per
cent, the ISBA did not convene a conference to celebrate the fact,
and people who were not around at the time may not appreciate its
significance.
It
should not be necessary to suggest to the managing director of a
giant and highly successful company that he does not seem fully to
understand the economics of the UK’s television
medium, that the problem that appears so to concern him is not a
major problem at all, and that the solution he is advocating would
be of no benefit to his company or to anybody else. But possibly
he has been badly advised, so let us consider the implications of
the accompanying chart (Exhibit
1)
Commercial Television Associates
12
|
.
The
level of overall display advertising spend, as every schoolboy
ought to know, varies (squarishly) with the level of overall
consumer expenditure, modified by changes in the levels of
corporate profits, and both the press and the television halves of
the chart show how since 1982 adspend has moved in accordance with
movement in the national economy – a long upward trend to the
late eighties, a most uncomfortable fall for the following three
or four years, and a steady recovery thereafter.
The
press display picture is clear enough. Increases in adspend are
determined by how much more money marketing directors can persuade
finance directors to release, and result in more volume – more
billions of pages of advertisements distributed. But while
increased demand puts up rates in the early years of a cycle,
these themselves result in the creation of more press media
opportunities – which lead to reduction in rates and (in this
instance) very little change thereafter. In this medium, as in all
other sectors of the advertising market as a whole, adspend is the
independent variable, but in this case volume is determined by how
much can be bought at given rates. And the more volume is
demanded, the more can be supplied – generally at a decreasing
marginal cost, because that is the nature of the press.
The
mechanics of the television medium are different. Again, adspend
is determined by the state of the economy, and follows the same
general pattern as that of the press (though television’s share
of the Press Display + TV total has risen over the fifteen years
from 40 to 48 per cent). But volume is determined by the hours of
programmes broadcast, the number of people the television
contractors can get to watch those programmes, and the number of
minutes in the broadcast hour they are permitted to devote to
commercials: over the fifteen years from 1982 to 1997 that volume
has increased by 40 per cent. But the volume delivered cannot be
varied to match varying demand – not even when demand slackens,
since the market must clear itself each day, at whatever rates it
can get.
What
have caused the increases in volume supplied are, from 1982 to
1984 the arrival of Channel 4 and TV-am, and thereafter increases
in broadcasting hours and extensions in the permitted advertising
minutes per hour (originally 6, but now effectively 7.2). Thus
with a total advertising budget determined by how much money can
be spared, at any particular stage in the economic cycle, to be
spent on buying share of voice in competitive situations (which is
what advertising is, fundamentally, about) and a volume of supply
which is virtually fixed over the immediate term, what in effect
operates as an auction determines the price per thousand paid. In
the case of the press, expenditure divided by rate tells the
market how much space it is buying: in the case of television,
expenditure divided by the advertising volume available tells the
market what rate it is paying. In this latter case, it is not that
greedy media proprietors are holding the advertiser to ransom when
the economy is buoyant (or that they are being benevolent in times
of recession): the true villains from the advertiser’s point of
view are other advertisers, whether or not they are fellow-members
of the ISBA.
But
that is not always recognised. Given that the supply of television
opportunities is limited because getting on for half of all the
television delivered is provided by the BBC,
which does not carry commercials, and that advertising on
commercial channels is (mostly) limited to seven minutes in the
hour, if you believe this means that UK advertisers are severely
disadvantaged you will suppose that the remedy is simple – let
the BBC carry advertising, and extend the minuteage per hour to
nine. This will result in what looks like an obvious solution to
the problem (though in fact it begs the question) – a massive
increase in the availability of advertising opportunities, and an
automatic decrease in rates. So all will be well, and all manner
of things will be well.
Commercial Television Associates
13
|
To
put it gently, perhaps
not. It is difficult to imagine P&G deciding to save money by
buying the same weight of advertising at the new low rate if
Unilever decides to maintain its spending level and buy more
weight with it. So they both buy more weight: does either benefit?
This
last scenario understates the possibilities. Between 1982 and 1987
the volume of television advertising (commercial home minutes, or
impacts, or whatever) increased by 21 per cent, principally as a
result of the arrival and running-in of Channel 4 and TV-am. Over
the same period the volume of commercial home minutes bought for
instant coffee rose by 55 per cent, for petfoods by 57 per cent,
for rte cereals by 59 per cent, and for heavy-duty detergents by
101 per cent. And, of course, they spent between them a lot more
money, though that was largely a consequence of the booming
economy. It is noteworthy that these product categories are
essentially oligopolies, if not virtually duopolies, and such
exercises in market power make a nonsense of the suggestion mooted
last time around that increasing the supply of television
advertising opportunities would reduce barriers to market entry
– not that market leaders are necessarily keen on reducing such
barriers anyway.
A
note on the difficulties of foreseeing consequences. It was
thought that the arrival of satellite television would increase
the supply of television impacts and (in due course) lead to a
reduction in rates. But the curve of television advertising volume
in the chart (which naturally includes satellite) shows a halt to
growth after 1994 and a marked drop in 1996. While satellite now
takes almost a fifth of all non-BBC viewing, it provided in 1996
only about 12 per cent of all weighted impacts – because a
considerable proportion of satellite transmissions do not carry
advertising, being otherwise funded. Most of the 8.8 per cent
increase in 1996 in costs per thousand in real terms (11.4 per
cent at current prices) results from this – not at all what was
looked for by those who were so enthusiastic about its
introduction.
It
is worth noting (since the odd figure is always a handy thing to
have around) that the patterns of viewing shares across the past
twenty years have been: 1976, BBC 46 per cent, commercial channel
(ITV) 54 per cent; 1986, BBC 45 per cent, commercial channels (ITV
+ Channel 4) 55 per cent; 1996, BBC 45 per cent, commercial
channels (ITV + Channel 4 + satellite) 55 per cent – of which
satellite’s share is about 11 per cent. As Gertrude Stein
didn’t quite say, a market is a market is a market. “
Commercial Television Associates
14
|
Commercial Television Associates
15
|
“The
Simple Economics of Television Advertising
(ADMAP
October 1988)
Harry Henry
What
follows addresses only one aspect of television – the simple
economics of television advertising. For simple they basically
are, though failure to see the wood for the trees frequently
obfuscates the issue.
Television
is one advertising medium among several, and must not be looked at
in isolation. However, what is relevant here is not all
advertising but consumer display advertising – that is,
all advertising on television, display advertising in the consumer
press, and the modest contributions from posters, radio and
cinema.
And
one thing must be clear from the outset: it is essentially a tool
of competition within particular markets. With rare exceptions it
has little effect on the total size of individual markets, while
expenditure with non-competitive objectives is so small a
proportion of the whole as to be largely immaterial. Recognition
of these realities is essential to an understanding of what
advertising is all about.
How
adspend is determined
The
pattern of consumer display advertising over the past eighteen
years is shown in Figure 1. This has
increased very rapidly: even at constant (1980) prices it has
virtually doubled from 1.4 billion pounds in 1970 to 2.7 billion
in 1987. The figure at current prices was 4.1 billion pounds in
1987, and will reach over 4.5 billion in 1988.
Also
shown in this chart is the curve of total consumers’ expenditure
on goods and services in the
UK
.
There is an obvious tendency for the two curves to move in
sympathy, but they do so at different rates. Whereas between 1970
and 1987 consumers’ expenditure in real terms increased by some
46 per cent, consumer display advertising in real terms increased
by no less than 96 per cent.
Clearly,
the ratio of consumer display advertising to total consumers’
expenditure has risen over the period. This ratio can be regarded
as a proxy for the advertising-to-sales ratio of British consumer
markets as a whole, and we can see from Figure 2 how it has
in fact risen – from 1.2 per cent in 1970 to 1.6 per cent in
1987, an increase of 33 per cent. But what is particularly
noteworthy here is that, four exceptional years apart, this curve
matches almost exactly the curve of total consumers’
expenditure. The exceptional years were 1974, 1975 and 1976 –
the catastrophe years of the oil crisis and its aftermath – and
1979, when commercial television was off the air for almost two
months because of a strike.
This
means that a given percentage change in the level of consumers’
expenditure produces an almost identical percentage change in the ratio
of advertising to consumers’ expenditure, the overall
advertising-to-sales ratio: an increase in consumers’
expenditure results in advertising taking an increased proportion
of an increased base. In other words, advertising expenditure
varies as the square of consumers’ expenditure, which is
why I have labelled this phenomenon ‘the square law’. A highly
satisfactory and remarkably simple model follows from this, but
the relationship between the two measures is very clearly
illustrated in Figure 3.
Commercial Television Associates
16
|
The
model (shown in Figure 4) is not
difficult to grasp, involves no complex mathematical symbols, and
does not require a computer. Simply, advertising expenditure in
millions of pounds equals roughly one-tenth of the square of
consumers’ expenditure in billions. It is not hard to see how
closely the model fits the reality: in fact, leaving aside the
four catastrophe years, the correlation between the two is .996,
which is about as near perfection as one could hope to get in an
imperfect world. It does not provide for catastrophe years, and
should not. A model that does is a model that must be regarded
with the utmost suspicion and will be quite useless for normal
purposes.
It
is, of course, one thing to uncover the existence of the square
law, but quite another to discover why it exists or in what
circumstances it will be repealed. What can be said is that
the relationship has been maintained, catastrophes apart, for
almost 20 years.
One
explanation can, however, be found. There is no reason why an
increasing level of sales revenue in real terms should confront
the typical manufacturer with increasing costs per unit sold –
rather the reverse, in fact. But with advertising the situation is
different. Although what the advertiser is technically buying are
advertising opportunities – time on television, pages in
newspapers and magazines – these are not objectives in their own
right. What he is seeking is a share of voice in the market place,
matching – to whatever extent is deemed necessary – that
sought, competitively, by rival firms. And the total of shares of
voice is finite, and in no way related to the supply of
advertising opportunities. However loud the combined voice may be,
the various individual shares cannot add up to more than 100 per
cent – or, for that matter, to less.
Thus
so long as he can be satisfied that a maintained or increased
advertising spend is profitable in relation to maintained or
increased sales, or that a decrease in spend would result in a
sales loss outweighing the saving, and so long as he can lay hands
on the necessary funds, so long he will compete for what he
considers an appropriate share of the available supply of
advertising opportunities, however much that supply may expand.
Comparison
with the
USA
Since
an extraordinary amount of nonsense is talked about international
comparisons, ignoring the problems involved in such comparisons in
terms of exchange rates and of the international differences in
effective values delivered by a minute of television time or a
page of press advertising, we might take a quick look at how the
general pattern of advertising in the UK compares with that of the
USA, a country regarded by so many people as the paradigm of
deregulation and competition.
Figure
5
gives a fair impression of those patterns: the use of indices and
ratios by-passes the problem of exchange rates. Between 1981 and
1986 total advertising expenditure at constant prices rose by 40
per cent in the States: it rose by 40 per cent in the
UK
.
And expenditure on television as a percentage of total advertising
expenditure, around 32 per cent in both countries in 1981, had
risen to around 35 per cent in both countries by 1986. Expenditure
on television rose over the period by 54 per cent in the
US
and by 56 per cent in the
UK
– hardly a material differences – and expenditure on all other
media, though it rose rather less, also did so at roughly the same
rate in both countries.
Commercial Television Associates
17
|
The
implications of this are clear. Whether we are talking about total
advertising expenditure, or expenditure on television, or
expenditure on other media, or television as proportion of total
spend, the increases are virtually identical in the two countries.
If there is any evidence here to suggest that changing the
structure of the television system in Britain to something closer
to the American would in any way affect the patterns of
expenditure I must confess that I cannot see it.
The
same similarity emerges when we bring in the square law. Figure 6 shows
advertising expenditure as a proportion of gross domestic product
rather than of consumers’ expenditure, but that makes little
difference to the shape of the curves. Because gross domestic
product per head is greater in American than in
Britain
,
the advertising percentages are higher there than here – a fact
which itself supports the square law. But, equally for television
and for all other media, the proportions have risen over the
period in both cases, and in each case to the same extent in each
country.
Dividing
the adspend pot
Figure
7
shows how total consumer display advertising in the
UK
has been divided between the three main media categories. The
figures for 1979 have been omitted because of the television
strike of that year: apart from this, the most immediately
noticeable aspect is the remarkable stability of the trends –
which persist even through the catastrophe years of 1974 to 1976.
But the most surprising thing about the television curve is that
while the supply of television advertising opportunities increased
between 1971 and 1973 by 21 per cent (as a result of the
introduction in 1972 of afternoon broadcasting) and again by 21
per cent between 1982 and 1984 (as a result of the arrival of
Channel 4 and TV-am) these dramatic increases in supply – far
greater than could now be expected, for example, from the arrival
of a fifth channel – had no visible effect on the trend of
television’s share of expenditure. More money, in real terms,
continued to be spent.
However,
to put these trends into perspective it is helpful to look not
just at shares but at actual expenditures in real terms. These are
shown in Figure 8: the
figures for 1988 are estimates, but will not be far out. There is
a good deal of year-on-year variation, but we might note that the
effects of the 1970/71 recession, the 1973 boom, and the 1974/76
crisis, were the same both for television and for other media. In
1979 most of the money suddenly denied to television, in the short
term, by the strike of that year went into other media: some of
it, indeed, had to be so committed into 1980.
Figure 9
shows what the general pattern looks like if we cut through the
year-on-year fluctuations to get at the longer-term trends. The
phases during which the rates of change have increased are
identical for television and for all other media combined, but the
increases have been consistently greater for television,
reflecting what we already know about television’s steadily
increasing share of total spend.
The
supply of advertising opportunities
There
is only one reason for the steady fall in the press share of the
increased total: advertisers have progressively preferred to
allocate their advertising budgets to television. There has been
no significant change over the period in the total circulation of
newspapers and consumer magazines, which between them distributed
over 11
billion
copies in 1987. But in any case the supply of press advertising
opportunities is neither constrained nor fostered by press
circulations: if advertisers want more press impacts, it is
normally easy enough for these to be provided by the addition of
extra pages.
Commercial Television Associates
18
|
Thus
the volume of press advertising opportunities delivered, shown in Figure
10 in indexed form, represents what advertisers, of
their own free will, have chosen to buy, there being no
constraints of any sort. The year-on-year fluctuations essentially
reflect fluctuations of total advertising expenditure, themselves
linked to overall consumers’ expenditure by the square law. But
the supply of television advertising opportunities is a quite
different matter. These we measure in commercial home minutes: the
chart shows these in indexed form, and while there were 98 billion
of them in 1970, the figure for 1988 will be about 152 billion.
The
factors which determine the supply of commercial home minutes are
the size of the total television audience, the proportion of
viewing homes switched to a commercial channel at any point in
time, and the number of minutes in the hour in which commercials
may be transmitted. All this is largely independent of anything
the contractor might do: while he endeavours to optimise the
proportion of viewing homes which constitute his audience he
cannot dictate it, and its variations are much affected by
external factors – such as, of recent years, the BBC’s policy
of playing the ratings game rather more vigorously. And the
numbers of commercial minutes transmitted are controlled
not by anything the advertisers can do but by the regulations
about the number permitted in the hour and the IBA requirement
that all the time permitted shall be disposed of. The mechanism
through which television advertising opportunities are bought and
sold is totally irrelevant.
What
emerges very clearly from Figure
10 is that while the volume of press advertising
opportunities which advertisers have chosen to buy in a totally
free and highly competitive market has increased since 1970 by
some 25 per cent, the volume of television advertising
opportunities with which advertisers collectively have been supplied
has increased by no less than 50 per cent. The casual observer
might wonder what they are grumbling about.
Space
does not permit detailed discussion of the year-on-year variations
in commercial home minuteage though it may be observed that the 6
per cent decline between 1973 and 1976 simply reflects the 7 per
cent drop in ITV audience which produced such squeals of anguish
at the time from advertisers and their agencies. And ITV came back
after the 1979 strike (the figures for that year are omitted here)
with substantially lower audiences, absolutely and as share of
total viewing, than it had been getting before the strike. But
none of this had any effect on the economics of television
advertising, as is clear from Figure
11 which smooths out the short-term changes. Although
both the supply of television advertising opportunities and
expenditure on television have trended upwards over the past 18
years, there is no correlation whatever between the two. And
certainly there is no indication that increases in supply result
in decreases in expenditure. A more widespread recognition of this
reality might have done something to check the vast amount of
nonsense currently being talked about the future.
Commercial Television Associates
19
|
The
production costs phenomenon
That
advertising expenditures increase in order to mop up the
increasing amounts of money which advertisers as a whole have
available and which they judge it expedient to use, competitively,
in the battle for share of voice and hence share of market, must
be regarded as a variant of Parkinson’s Law. But very
significant corroborative evidence emerges when we look at
production costs – the costs of designing and making the actual
press advertisements and television commercials. The left-hand
side of Figure
12 shows the media costs per message delivered – the
same thing, in effect, as the advertising rates per thousand. Over
the ten years since 1977 press rates, at constant prices, have
increased by 25 per cent. Television rates have increased by 82
per cent -hence, as they say, these tears. But it is the
right-hand side, production costs per message delivered,
which shows what happens when there is so much money sloshing
about that financial managements do not think it necessary to
impose unkind restraints on market managements.
In
the case of the press, production costs per message delivered
changed very little between 1977 and 1982: since then, however,
they have increased rapidly, the 1987 figure being 60 per cent
higher than that of 1977. There are complications with the
television curve, because in the strike year of 1979 money was
spent on producing commercials which could not then be fully
exposed, while less were made in 1980 because of the stocks left
over from the previous year: the dotted line averages these
years. But that is hardly material: the important thing is that
television production costs per message delivered, at constant
prices, were in 1987 no less than 120 per cent above their 1977
level.
Against
increases of this order the lip-service currently being paid to
the need for better housekeeping in the administration of
production are immaterial, having something in common with a Board
instruction to economise on paper-clips and switch off the lights
when leaving the toilets. There are only two likely explanations:
either more commercials are being made to fill equivalent amounts
of time, or commercials are being made more expensively – in
terms of high-priced artistes and directors, exotic locations,
fiendishly complex technology and graphics, and the like. Either
explanation implies the concurrence of the advertiser, who must be
presumed to know what he is doing and to find either or both worth
while in terms of increased effectiveness – or of matching
competition. For there are no monopolies material to rising costs
in the advertisement production processes, no limitations on the
number of suppliers who can enter the business, and no
statutorily-imposed sales structures. If advertisers are prepared
to spend money in this way it is because they judge this will give
them an advantage over their competitors in the battle for
consumers’ hearts and minds.
An
actor paid 75,000 for a day’s work can obtain such remuneration
only because some advertiser judges his particular services are
worth the money. Equally, when one marketing director complains
that a single commercial costs his company 300,000, while another
protests that the million pounds he spent on four commercials
could have been more usefully spent in other directions, it is not
in itself obvious why they, the executives responsible for such
expenditures, actually authorise them. But both media expenditure
and production expenditure are governed by the same factors –
the perceived need to compete for share of the consumer’s mind,
the availability of resources to do so, and the judgment that
these resources can be more cost-effectively allocated in that way
than in other directions. The money is there to be spent, and
spent it will be, both on increasingly expensive commercials and,
more significantly, on bidding against other firms for share of
television voice.
Commercial Television Associates
20
|
In
fact, the price/supply equation for television can be very simply
expressed.
One
could say:
TV
expenditure = audience delivered times TV costs per thousand which
is arithmetically correct but logically nonsense. The correct form
of the equation is:
TV
cost per thousand = TV expenditure divided by audience delivered
and there is no connection of any sort between expenditure and
audience: they are both independent variables, and cost per
thousand is a dependent variable.
Misunderstanding
‘competition’
It
may be wondered where in all this I fit the concept of
competition. The short answer is that I don’t: it is wholly
irrelevant at the level of the market, though I am prepared to
concede that it might have some marginal effect on the outer
fringes.
Since
we no longer burn heretics at the stake, it is not particularly
courageous of me to suggest that ‘competition’ is not
invariably the answer to a maiden’s prayer, or to ask what the
devil people think they are talking about when they use the word
in connection with television. Expenditure on advertising is in no
way related to the supply of advertising opportunities, and the
same amount of money will be spent however supply changes. And
while increases in television supply provide more opportunities
for that same money, this is of no advantage to advertisers in
their search for share of voice: they will all benefit’
equally. When increases have occurred in the past, they have been
snapped up by the big boys pro-rata -sometimes more than pro-rata.
And the mechanisms through which those advertising opportunities
are sold are almost wholly irrelevant.
This,
however, is true only in one sense. Where the supplier’s sales
organisation can exert some influence is on the demand
side. The propensity of advertisers to buy television time is a
function of their general willingness to spend money on
advertising as a tool of competition, but it is also a function of
their relative preference for television as against other media
– which preference has increased steadily over time regardless
of changes in the volume of television opportunities available.
Thus it has been an important task of the sales organisations to
promote that relative preference, and the more successfully they
can do that the greater will be the advertiser’s propensity to
spend money on television rather than on other media – and thus
push up what are seen as rates.
The
efforts, which have been made by the television companies over the
years to persuade the users of other media that television is a
suitable medium for them, typify this. Television’s share of
total TV and consumer press display advertising on motor cars, for
example, has grown from 4 per cent in 1969 to 44 per cent in 1987.
And when, following the break up of the Stags consortium at the
end of 1981, Scottish Television sharpened its sales activities
(to the admiration of the advertising industry) it increased its
share of national revenue over the next three years by 20 per
cent, despite no increase in its share of national audience. In
other words, the rates per thousand which its advertisers paid
rose well ahead of the market as a direct consequence of the sort
of vigorous activity implicit in the concept of competitive
selling.
Commercial Television Associates
21
|
Five
propositions arise from the evidence I have analysed.
- What determines advertising spend? The amount of
money advertisers can find and are prepared to spend in
competition with other advertisers for share of voice.
- What determines television spend? The proportion of
their total spend which advertisers judge will be more
efficient against competition in TV rather than in other
media.
- What determines TV rates? The amount of money
advertisers are prepared to spend, competitively, on
television, divided by the audiences which that money
provides.
- The effects of more vigorous selling of television
time? An increase in the propensity of advertisers to spend
money on television.
- The effect of more money being spent on
television? Increases in TV ‘rates’.
A
fifth channel?
A
word might be said here about the likely consequence of a fifth
terrestrial channel. Look first in Table 1 at what history has to
tell us. Between 1971 and 1973 the supply of commercial home
minutes rose by 21 per cent: expenditure on television rose in
real terms by 26 per cent. But press display advertising also
rose, by 25 per cent. 1973 was the peak of an advertising boom,
not matched in speed of growth until the one we are currently
experiencing. And between 1982 and 1984 the supply again rose by
21 per cent: this time television expenditure rose by 21 per cent,
while press display again rose by roughly the same amount – 24
per cent. I reiterate: changes in supply have no effect on the
levels of television spend, and certainly do not bring them
down.
TABLE
1: EFFECTS OF MAJOR CHANGES IN SUPPLY OF TELEVISION AUDIENCE
|
1971
– 1973
|
1982
– 1984
|
TELEVISION:
|
|
|
No.
of CHM
|
+21%
|
+21%
|
Spend
(at constant prices)
|
+26%
|
+21%
|
Cost
per thousand
|
+5%
|
0
|
CONSUMER
PRESS DISPLAY:
|
|
|
Spend
(at constant prices)
|
+25%
|
+24%
|
It
is somewhat improbable that a fifth channel would increase the
total amount of television viewing to any significant extent: even
seeking virgin audiences would have little overall effect. And on
the assumption that the fifth channel gains the same share of
audience as BBC2 or Channel 4, and that it takes share from the
BBC and the ITV network pro-rata, it will increase the supply of
commercial home minutes by barely more than 9 per cent. Seeing how
little have been the effects of increases of 21 per cent in the
past on the levels of television spend – none at all, in fact
– what can anybody in his right mind suppose will be the effect
of a mere 9 per cent? Double that figure of 9 per cent if you
like: twice zero is still no more than zero.
Commercial Television Associates
22
|
One
final point. At the end of 1987 the supply of commercial home
minutes was increased by an extension of broadcasting hours and by
an increase in the permitted number of advertising minutes in the
hour. As a result the number of commercial home minutes delivered
in the first half of 1988 was 5.4 per cent more than it had been
in the first half of 1987. Did this bring down the level of
television spend? It did not. That level increased by almost 15
per cent, what time press display advertising increase by no more
than 13 per cent.
There
is a lesson here.”
Commercial Television Associates
23
|
NOTES & EXHIBITS
FIGURE
1; TOTAL CONSUMERS’ EXPENDITURE AND CONSUMER DISPLAY ADVERTISING
At constant (1980) prices
Commercial Television Associates
24
|
FIGURE 2; TOTAL CONSUMERS’ EXPENDITIRE AT
CONSTANT PRICES AND CONSUMER DISPLAY ADVERTISING AS A PERCENTAGE
OF IT
Commercial Television Associates
25
|
FIGURE 3; RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN TOTAL
CONSUMERS’ EXPENDITURE AND CONSIMER DISPLAY ADVERTISING
Commercial Television Associates
26
|
FIGURE
4; CONSUMER DISPLAY ADVERTISING INCLUDING PRODUCTION AT CONSTANT
(1980) PRICES MODEL AND ACTUAL
Commercial Television Associates
27
|
Figure
5
Commercial Television Associates
28
|
FIGURE
6; ADVERTISING EXPENDITURE AS PERCENTAGE OF GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT
Commercial Television Associates
29
|
Figure
7
Commercial Television Associates
30
|
FIGURE
8; CONSUMER DISPLAY ADVERTISING EXPENDITURE
(including
production costs)
AT
CONSTANT PRICES
Commercial Television Associates
31
|
FIGURE
9; CONSUMER DISPLAY ADVERTISING EXPENDITURE
(including
production costs)
AT
CONSTANT PRICES LONG TERM TRENDS
Commercial Television Associates
32
|
FIGURE
10; INDICES OF ADVERTISING VOLUMES DELIVERED AND CONSUMER PRESS
DISPLAY (1970 = 100)
Commercial Television Associates
33
|
FIGURE
11; TELEVISION PHASES INDICES (1971 = 100) OF COMMERCIAL MINUTES
AND TV ADVERTISING EXPENDITURE
AT
CONSTANT PRICES
Figure
12
Commercial Television Associates
34
|
SECTION
7
THE
COMMERCIAL TELEVISION ASSOCIATES
The
Commercial Television Associates was formed to guide commercial
broadcasting companies strategy in responding to the problems and
opportunities of the new era.
Such
advice falling within the following categories;
1)
Maximising airtime sales revenue.
2)
Innovatory initiatives responding to the
fragmentation of viewing audiences.
3)
Multi channel and IP broadcasting.
4)
International opportunities.
5)
The development of complimentary businesses.
Its
founders have unsurpassed experience, knowledge and expertise in
regard to the commercial aspects of television. They have been
responsible both jointly and individually for a number of major
commercial initiatives in broadcasting, the marketing of
commercial airtime, media planning and buying.
MIKE YERSHON
Prior
to setting up Media Assessment Ltd, Mike worked for McCann
Erickson (twice as Media Director with a 20 year span in between
and on the first occasion with a pan-European responsibility) and
Collect Dickenson Pearce and Leo Burnett (as Vice Chairman in
charge of Media, Research and Sales Promotion departments).
He
formed Yershon Media Management and Yershon Media Buying which
were later sold to TMDH plc, the largest independent media buyer
in 1988. Mike joined the plc board. Three years later TMDH was
sold to Aegis to form the
UK
end of
Europe
’s largest buyers of media. Yershon Media still traded as a
separate brand with Mike as Chairman. The TMDH brand was renamed
Carat
UK
with Mike as founder director.
In
parallel he was World Wide Media Controller for Guinness with
particular reference to
Europe
.
He
has introduced a number of major innovations in the media
advertising business.
Persuading
the commercial television companies to change spot lengths from
15/30//45/60 to 20/30/40/50/60 seconds.
At
Collett Dickenson Pearce became the first centralized media buyer
acting for Reckitt and Colman in this role.
Revitalized the outdoor
media by forming Portland Outdoor, jointly owned by Collett
Dickinson Pearce and J Walter Thompson agencies, where he was
chairman.
Launching the
UK
’s first specialist strategic media consultancy Yershon Media
Management, for several years the only agency of its kind.
Appointed
advisor to the commercial sub-committee of the Football league.
Proposed that games should be taken out of Saturday afternoon
fixture list and split between the BBC and ITV.
Subsequently he advised the
League on the exploitation of the rights worldwide.
Commercial Television Associates
35
|
JIM
SHAW
Jim
has considerable experience of commercial broadcasting from
involvement in a number of countries.
In the
UK
he was Director of Sales and Marketing at Thames Television.
In Europe, Asia and the USA, where he was chairman of the
companies he set up to market the computerized airtime sales
system he developed; along with James T Shaw, ex-VP Sales ABC
Television USA and Pete Cash the ex-head of the TVB the American
Television Bureau of advertising.
Whilst
at
Thames
, chairman at one time or another of the industry committees
concerned with Marketing, Finance, Research, Copy Clearance and
New Technology.
He
pioneered the use of commercial television by a number of
industries including those for motorcars, finance and direct
response.
He
was a Director of the McCann Erickson advertising agency,
Molinaire, a post production facilities company and SAWA, the
Screen Advertising World Awards festival in
France
.
Founder
member of the European Commercial Broadcasters Group.
He
founded SKY Direct Satellite TV and was head of TV Public
Relations for the British Advertising Industry.
Commercial Television Associates
36
|
|